Home » EUROPE » The Centripetal Theory of Governance: A Borderless Union
ESTpicture

The Centripetal Theory of Governance: A Borderless Union

Many art­icles have been writ­ten from dif­fer­ent sources on the European crisis and its ori­gins, but most of them base their argu­ments on per­sonal stand­points derived from fin­an­cial news and offi­cials’ speeches. That is exactly what I have been doing for the last few months. What we see is two dis­tant author­it­ies’ com­ments on the same topic, European crisis, with dif­fer­ent resources and basis. These two author­it­ies, aca­demia and the ‘real’ world, do not seem to be linked to each other on the mat­ter, but of course, this is not the case. For instance, there is much that aca­demia can con­trib­ute to the under­stand­ing of the ori­gins of the European eco­nomic crisis. It seems unlikely that one would find a com­pre­hens­ive art­icle that brings the two sides together on the ground, but it is pos­sible non­ethe­less. My inten­tion, of course, is not to take this respons­ib­il­ity; but rather to con­trib­ute to the research of the miss­ing pieces of the puzzle by high­light­ing the com­mon points that link the two sides.

I star­ted to think about the reflec­tion of the European crisis in the aca­demic world right after I came across the influ­en­tial book of George Tse­belis, Veto Players: How political institutions work?[1]. Even though the book cov­ers a wide range of top­ics, it  under­scores the key points of each one of them. In chapter eight, the author explains mac­roe­co­nomic out­comes by touch­ing upon the rela­tion­ship between debts, defi­cits and num­ber of veto play­ers[2]. Indeed, accord­ing to the author’s the­ory, “more veto play­ers will lead to more iner­tia, and there­fore coun­tries with high levels of debt (Italy) will con­tinue to have high defi­cits while coun­tries with low level of debt (Switzer­land) will con­tinue to have low levels of defi­cit”[3]. There­fore, hav­ing more play­ers who have a say in decision-making pro­cess will lead to a dif­fi­culty in legis­la­tion and this will res­ult in ‘policy iner­tia’. This should hold true regard­less of where it is applied.

The second point that I would like to draw atten­tion to is the struc­ture of the EU, which has been criticized for being the primary cause of the European eco­nomic crisis. A strong tend­ency towards rethink­ing this struc­ture by emphas­iz­ing its inflex­ib­il­ity has emerged. For instance, the Euro­zone could be blamed first for restrict­ing its members.

First of all, abol­ish­ing the mon­et­ary union and allow­ing the mem­ber states to act much more freely might be against the nature of the EU. The dir­ec­tion of integ­ra­tion should be from a decent­ral­ized sys­tem to a cent­ral­ized one, for there exis­ted some attempts towards European fed­er­al­ism dur­ing the first pro­cess of European integ­ra­tion[4]. Doubts not­with­stand­ing, the EU, as a nas­cent fed­eral state[5] is thought to pre­serve its cent­ral author­ity in order to hold mem­ber states together. Accord­ing to McKay, the EU has set a suc­cess­ful example of “trans­form­a­tion from an inter­na­tional organ­iz­a­tion to a fed­eral like state”[6]. Since the sep­ar­ated power sys­tem fosters  struggle between main act­ors, pub­lic admin­is­tra­tion is more likely to be effect­ive in cent­ri­petal organ­iz­a­tions. In com­par­at­ive fed­er­al­ism ana­lysis, unit­ary and cent­ri­petal con­sti­tu­tions show more sound struc­tures in resolv­ing coordin­a­tion prob­lems than fed­eral and separatist con­sti­tu­tions. Besides, cent­ri­petal organ­iz­a­tions help to medi­ate con­flicts, elim­in­ate rivalry atti­tudes and foster cooper­a­tion. On the other hand, decent­ral­ized organ­iz­a­tions are likely to exper­i­ence cor­rup­tion and coordin­a­tion prob­lems. This is reflec­ted, for instance, by the fiscal prob­lems in the EU due to a lack of fiscal coordin­a­tion among the mem­bers of the Eurozone.

Though the com­par­at­ive study of fed­er­al­ism can­not fully enlighten one as to how the  EU’s struc­tural prob­lems lead to mul­ti­far­i­ous crisis within the union, it can provide us with a broader under­stand­ing of centralized-decentralized insti­tu­tions. The research con­duc­ted on fed­er­al­ism stud­ies has an import­ant place in the gov­ern­ing of the EU and its future. Cent­ri­petal insti­tu­tions, where the abso­lute author­ity in policy-making is given to a single iden­tity, foster more effi­cient admin­is­tra­tion and avoid per­son­al­istic goals. There­fore, the EU should be cent­ral­ized rather than leav­ing its author­ity to mem­ber states for some flexibility.

The cent­ri­petal gov­ernance the­ory in polit­ical sci­ence provides us with cru­cial argu­ments which let us broadly dis­cern how polit­ical form­a­tions occur and how far they sur­vive in a col­lect­ive sys­tem. Appar­ently, organ­iz­a­tions con­sist­ing of diver­gent parts such as the EU should pre­serve their abso­lute author­it­ies to hold the parts together. EU’s mem­ber states dif­fer in their mar­ket sizes, pro­duc­tion capa­cit­ies, spend­ing levels and debt ratios; most of which have cru­cial impacts on the European eco­nomic tur­moil. The only way is to undergo an exten­ded reform in the struc­ture of the EU before the frag­ment­a­tion of the union becomes a fact.

–  Tevfik Murat Yildirim

(Featured photo: AttributionNoncommercialNo Derivative Works Open Days – European Week of Cities and Regions, Creative Commons, Flickr)

[1] Tse­belis, G. (2002) Veto Play­ers: How Polit­ical Insti­tu­tions Work. Prin­ceton Uni­ver­sity Press

[2] To quote the author on the defin­i­tion of veto play­ers: “In order to change policies – or, as we will say hence­forth, to change the (legis­lat­ive) status quo- a cer­tain num­ber of indi­vidual or col­lect­ive act­ors have to agree to the pro­posed change. I call such act­ors veto play­ers. Veto play­ers are spe­cified in a coun­try by the con­sti­tu­tion (the Pres­id­ent, the House, and the Sen­ate in the US) or by the polit­ical sys­tem (the dif­fer­ent parties that are mem­bers of a gov­ern­ment coali­tion in West­ern Europe”.

[3] Ibid.

[4] This is expressed, for instance, by the Hague Con­gress in 1948 (although its out­come is far from sat­is­fact­ory for the fed­er­al­ists) and the dif­fer­ent nego­ti­ations that led to the cre­ation of the European Eco­nomic Com­munity (Beyen Plan for European Polit­ical Com­munity [that unfor­tu­nately collapsed]).

[5] There is an enorm­ous lit­er­at­ure on Fed­er­al­ism and the EU, gen­er­ally divided in two sides: One assum­ing that the EU is a nas­cent fed­eral state accord­ing to Riker’s fed­er­al­ism term, the other assum­ing that it is an inter­na­tional organ­iz­a­tion. The sys­tem­atic com­par­is­ons were car­ried out by Mckay (2001) and Tres­chel (2006). The sup­port­ers of the first view focus their atten­tion on EMU states, not all. The EU, accord­ing to many schol­ars, resembles a nation state: “Other schol­ars were quick to note that the new policy respons­ib­il­it­ies of the EU com­bined with a con­sti­tu­tional archi­tec­ture that looked for all intents and pur­poses like that of a nation state, jus­ti­fied clas­si­fy­ing the EU as a nas­cent fed­er­a­tion rather than a sui gen­eris vari­ety of inter­na­tional organization.”(see McKay, p.418).

[6] McKay, D. (2009) The SAGE Hand­book of Com­par­at­ive Polit­ics, Sage Pub­lic­a­tions Ltd, p.418.

About Guest Writer

Check Also

The Pariahs of the European Union

As the European Union (EU) struggles to dig itself out of an unimaginably large pit of ...